Aug 30, 2022
Back to the future: a heterodox economist rewrites Keynes’s General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money to serve as the basis for a macroeconomics for the twenty-first century. John Maynard Keynes’s General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money was the most influential economic idea of the twentieth century. But, argues Stephen Marglin, its radical implications were obscured by Keynes’s lack of the mathematical tools necessary to argue convincingly that the problem was the market itself, as distinct from myriad sources of friction around its margins.
Marglin fills in the theoretical gaps, revealing the deeper meaning of the General Theory. Drawing on eight decades of discussion and debate since the General Theory was published, as well as on his own research, Marglin substantiates Keynes’s intuition that there is no mechanism within a capitalist economy that ensures full employment. Even if deregulating the economy could make it more like the textbook ideal of perfect competition, this would not address the problem that Keynes identified: the potential inadequacy of aggregate demand.
Ordinary citizens have paid a steep price for the distortion of Keynes’s message. Fiscal policy has been relegated to emergencies like the Great Recession. Monetary policy has focused unduly on inflation. In both cases the underlying rationale is the false premise that in the long run at least the economy is self-regulating so that fiscal policy is unnecessary and inflation beyond a modest two percent serves no useful purpose.
Fleshing out Keynes’s intuition that the problem is not the warts on the body of capitalism but capitalism itself, Raising Keynes provides the foundation for a twenty-first-century macroeconomics that can both respond to crises and guide long-run policy.
Stephen A. Marglin is the Walter Barker Professor of Economics at Harvard University. His books include The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community and Growth, Distribution, and Prices. He is a past Guggenheim Fellow and member of the Harvard Society of Fellows.
“Marglin has taken 80 years of neoclassical distortions of Keynes, presented them with great clarity in their own language, and then pounded them into dust, pushing the detritus back into the faces of the high priests of the neoclassical synthesis, the New Keynesians, and the New Classical Economists. Raising Keynes issues a challenge that they would be cowardly to refuse—which is not to suggest that they won’t do their best to ignore it.”—James K. Galbraith, Project Syndicate
“Stephen Marglin’s magnum opus makes a powerful case that we cannot expect the economy to solve its own problems, and that instead economists and policymakers need to put persistent unemployment at the center of their thinking in order to both better understand the economy and to make a stronger case for using fiscal and monetary policy to change it for the better.”—Jason Furman, Harvard University, former Chairman of the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers
“This is a thought-stimulating reconstruction of John Maynard Keynes’s insight that market economies do not automatically gravitate to full-employment equilibrium even if prices are flexible. Stephen Marglin shows, with modern analytical tools and (yet) in an often entertaining style, how normal signal processing leads to real-time adjustments to shocks that can move a competitive economy out of equilibrium in the short run and into a different equilibrium in the long. He succeeds in demonstrating this without invoking all those frictions and imperfections so indispensable to New Keynesians. The book opens a wide array of unorthodox, but well-founded perspectives on past and current issues of economic policy. It is the fruit of life-long research, and it deserves a wide readership.”—Hans-Michael Trautwein, University of Oldenburg, Germany
“Raising Keynes is a work of great significance that anyone seriously interested in how capitalism functions and malfunctions should read carefully. Stephen Marglin succeeds in clarifying the central ideas in John Maynard Keynes’s revolutionary macroeconomic framework, while also extending and deepening those ideas in important ways, applying the ideas to our contemporary conditions, and also delivering devastating critiques of orthodox macroeconomic theory and practice. The book is also highly accessible for a work of this nature, without skimping at all on technical details—an almost impossible combination to pull off.”—Robert Pollin, University of Massachusetts Amherst
Table of Contents
TRANSCRIPT
Speaker 1:
I once attended lectures that Duncan Foley was getting on a book
called Growth Distribution and Prices, which was a great
experience. I was fascinated by the book and partly because of
Duncan's enthusiasm for the book, and that was written by Stephen
A. Marglin, and today I have the great privilege of speaking
Stephen Marglin about his newest book, which is Raising Keynes:,
K-E-Y-N-E-S, Twenty-First Century General Theory, Harvard
University Press 2021. Duncan referred to the Growth Distribution
and Prices, as a tour to force, and I think this is another tour to
force. Thank you for joining me. I should to give your status, your
past Guggenheim fellow and member of the Harvard Society of
Fellows. Steve A. Marglin is the Walter Barker professor of
economics at Harvard University. Welcome Steve.
Stephen Marglin:
Thank you very much [inaudible 00:01:18] Appreciate the
opportunity.
Speaker 1:
So how did this book come about?
Stephen Marglin:
Good question. So, as you indicated, the earlier book dealt
tangentially with Keynes and I'm a little embarrassed now I XX
think back about how little I really knew about Keynes at that
time, the book wasn't about Keynes, so I guess it was more
forgivable. I've been interested in Keynes and Keynes's theory and
the distortions of Keynes theory and the evolution of theory since
I was an undergraduate, which was in the 1950s. So off and on, I've
done various things along these lines, including giving a course at
Harvard, the early part of this century or the late part of the
last century maybe, I think it actually straddled the turn of the
century, and finally giving that up for lack of interest, not on my
part, but on the students' part, there just wasn't much interest in
Keynes. So I decided I had other projects and that sure, I could
continue my own interest in Keynes, but I wasn't going to inflict
it on an unwilling audience.
Stephen Marglin:
So I did turn to other things and that included giving an
undergraduate course, an alternative deck 10 as we call it, EC 101
is often generically referred to and I was coming back from a
lecture in that course on September 15th, 2008, the day that Lehman
brothers crashed or they crashed on the weekend, but this was when
the stuff hit the fan, and in the foyer of the Littauer Building,
the home of the Harvard Economics department, there was a group of
younger professors discussing, "Well, what are the consequences?
What's likely to happen as a result of this financial debacle?" And
I kind of eavesdropped. I didn't participate, I eavesdropped and
tried to see what the currents were and this was group of
economists, so there were different opinions to be sure, but I came
away from that conversation with two conclusions.
Stephen Marglin:
One, that the weight of that group was that it wasn't going to have
a big effect. This was a financial crisis, the real economy was in
pretty good shape. Yes, we were in a recession, but the real
problem were elsewhere, and this would write itself pretty quickly.
That was conclusion one. Conclusion two was that Keynes's moment
had come back, that there was going to be a reason why people would
be interested in Keynes. Things were not going to be as rosy as the
weight of opinion was.
Stephen Marglin:
So I decided that being, having just finished book called The
Dismal Science, on the problems of economics as a social science
and as an intellectual endeavor that leaves totally out of the
picture community and just finished that I was ready for another
project. And I thought, "Well, this is a time summarize my
interpretation of Keynes and put it out there for the public."
Stephen Marglin:
I thought that this was a project that was going to take two years
at the outside because I thought I knew what I wanted to say. Well,
I discovered after two years that I was still learning what I
wanted to say. I was learning a lot, but it was a moderately slow
process and I think it took me three or four years to figure out
really what I wanted to write and then another four or five years
to write it. So the book was over 10 years in preparation. So the
impetus, you could say the final cause was the crash of 2008 and
the reaction of the economics profession to it.
Speaker 1:
And this came out in 2021, the pandemic economy. This is also
extremely pertinent for that.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, I was putting the finishing touches because everything was
slowed down cause of the pandemic. I was putting the finishing
touches of this book in the spring of 2020, the pandemic had just
started. Was I going to revise it? And I thought, "Geez, if I start
revising now there's going to be no end to it." So there's really
nothing about the pandemic.
Speaker 1:
I understand that.
Stephen Marglin:
In fact the only reference to pandemic or anything like it is with
regard, I think, to the Black Death, if I remember. I do think it's
relevant, the issues that have come up since the pandemic, but
curiously, in a way, it's World War II and it's aftermath, which I
think is most relevant to the pandemic and it's aftermath in terms
the economic consequences.
Speaker 1:
Interesting. Well, I think heard... Well, a lot of people have said
this, but I guess it was Lucas who we trace it back to, that there
are no laissez-faire people, I guess, in a foxhole.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, you said there are no atheists in a foxhole actually. No. He
said... No, no. He said, yes, what did he say?
Speaker 1:
We're all [inaudible 00:07:05] in a foxhole or something like
Stephen Marglin:
Something like that, yes. I used this phrase in a response to an
interview Lamond and the question were in French and my answers
were in English when they were going to translate this, at which
they did, into French, they didn't have a clue what this meant
because the foxhole in French, the first definition is the hole to
which a fox goes.
Speaker 1:
Of course there are no-
Stephen Marglin:
And I had to straighten that out for them.
Speaker 1:
Right.
Stephen Marglin:
But yes, he did say that. And then he qualified that statement by
saying, "I don't think we're there yet," or something to that
effect, but yeah, there was a kind of 10 minute period. I think it
wasn't on the day of Lehman Brothers crash, but when things started
to unfold and it's clear that this was going to be a much more
consequential event than people had anticipated on September 14th
or September 12th and there was a kind of a 10 minute moment when I
think the economics profession was bewildered and open to new
ideas, but the ranks closed pretty quickly.
Speaker 1:
Did they? Okay. You've returned to teaching this to undergrads?
Stephen Marglin:
I did. I started teaching it not the next year, but I think maybe
in 2011 and I taught it all the way through the writing process.
I'm teaching a slightly different version of it now, which is a
seminar based thing in which I want to explore with undergraduates,
the possibilities of further research and what kinds of topics and
emerge from this book that people might do research on. I don't
know how that will go. We start classes day after tomorrow. So if
we come back and talk again in a couple weeks, I might have a
better fix on that or a couple of months, probably even
better.
Speaker 1:
Right. Well, were the undergraduates more interested in the course
while you were writing the book as opposed to when you were
teaching Keynes before?
Stephen Marglin:
Yes. It wasn't the kind of mass turnout that I hoped and feared
because I didn't want to teach a large class, but I would've been
gratified by the interest, but certainly there was a sustained
interest. I think the average turnout was, and this is of course an
upper class elective that nobody has to take and I think it ran
normally between 10 and 20. So that that's not a bad turnout for
this kind of course.
Stephen Marglin:
It was very heavy reading and I'm just reminded by my TF, that the
reading for this semester is much more than undergraduate courses
normally happening. So it was a good turnout and certainly in terms
of engagement, I felt that a number of the students really engaged
in the material and accomplished what I wanted to do, was to get
them to rethink everything they had thought they knew about
economics.
Speaker 1:
Absolutely. It does a great job of that. I kind of felt like it was
a textbook. Well, it's a lot of different things. It's a textbook
and it's a book on theory. I think that in economics, maybe in
other fields, if you say something is a textbook, that's kind of a
put down, but in economics, textbooks are very important.
Stephen Marglin:
And it is, as you say, it doesn't fit neatly into any category. I
wouldn't categorize it first and foremost as a textbook, that` I
hope it will be used as such. I may have some illusions about how
accessible it is to undergraduates. I think the fact that there was
a course that went along with the book made it much easier to get
the ideas across, but it's written purposely with the mathematics
all put in separate compartments so that people with really a
minimum of math can follow the argument, though I certainly
wouldn't claim it's bedtime reading.
Speaker 1:
Correct. Yeah, no, as I was reading it has a very economics feel.
It's models and it starts with one model and then layers another on
top and then goes back, layers another on top and it requires real
focus and it uses a lot of graphs, which we're used to in economics
as sort of an idea a way of getting the intuition.
Stephen Marglin:
That's something does come out of teaching it and teaching it as I
was going along because if I'm not going to use mathematics, which
is the normal way of presenting this kind of material nowadays,
what are the aids that I can use to get ideas across and graphs
seem to work. I don't know how it would was for you or how be for
others to read it on their own without-
Speaker 1:
A course
Stephen Marglin:
... a course, but the aim was to make it accessible to people who
wanted to put in the effort.
Speaker 1:
That's absolutely right. Yeah, I was saying I for the first time in
my life understood ISLM from one of your graphs.
Stephen Marglin:
Which is a step along the way. It's not the...
Speaker 1:
No, it is-
Stephen Marglin:
[inaudible 00:12:58]
Speaker 1:
... and it shows how much of a mere step along the way it is.
Right.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah and of course I had to relearn ISLM. That was one of the
things I figured out along the way. I thought I knew what it was,
but I realized I hadn't understand either how Hicks meant it or how
it had evolved into what it is in the textbooks, how it ought to be
used.
Speaker 1:
Yes. So if we think about, as you say, the fall and rise of Keynes,
I wasn't very interested in your explaining how Keynes was
interpreted. So if you read the general theory, it doesn't read
like a piece of economics today.
Stephen Marglin:
No.
Speaker 1:
And then the people-
Stephen Marglin:
There's a [inaudible 00:13:47]-
Speaker 1:
Go ahead.
Stephen Marglin:
... divide between the kind of economics that Keynes knew, believed
in, wrote.
Speaker 1:
Right.
Stephen Marglin:
This is not due to Keynes. This was in the works. The younger
generation was learning a whole new mode, which they then tried to
apply to Keynes.
Speaker 1:
Right and-
Stephen Marglin:
It was never an easy book to read for anybody, but for the present
generation, it just seems like it's-
Speaker 1:
You can't make heads or tails of it. Yeah.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah.
Speaker 1:
So then I love this section of your book with friends like
Modigliani, which is part of, I guess, what you had to go through
and recreate is Keynes's, this inscrutable book, how was it
converted into a modern model and what did it miss?
Stephen Marglin:
Right, that was one of the tasks I learned. I really hadn't
understood any of that and I had to reconstruct it. So I leapt
ahead myself and was thinking in the dynamic terms that I actually
end up presenting, amending, however you put it, Keynes, and I
didn't have the understanding of what Keynes was up to and what it
then became in the hands of the next generation, both friendly and
unfriendly critics.
Speaker 1:
Right. Now one of the things is you point out that Keynes did not
have the math available to him, even if he had wanted to capture
his insights. Tell us about what math that was.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, it's basically the mathematics of differential equations and
it's not that it didn't exist, but it was just being mobilized by
younger economists in the 1930s and to me, what interesting
mysterious, if you will, question is not why didn't Keynes deploy
this mathematics, which he didn't have, but why didn't the next
generation deploy it, which they had it, but they didn't deploy
it... Well, haltingly and fitfully in the 19-late sixties, early
seventies, but by then the currents were flowing in a different
direction and those got sidetracked and it was not picked up by the
third generation, if you will.
Stephen Marglin:
The second generation was Samuelson, Tobin, Solo, just to mention
three who Modigliani himself, just now four who won Nobel prizes, I
wouldn't say that it stopped contributing to economics, that's
certainly not true, but they were not the up and coming generation.
The up and coming generation was Lucas, Sergeant, Kidman, et
cetera, the rational expectations, new classical, the economics, if
you will, of neoliberalism.
Speaker 1:
Now you mentioned a book by Frank Fisher on this general topic or
on the-
Stephen Marglin:
Well, on the general topic of adjustment out of equilibrium, not
really on Keynes.
Speaker 1:
Oh, no. Right.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah, it sunk like a stone. Fisher was a very bright MIT economist
and who did many, many things and this was one that was never
picked up on.
Speaker 1:
Right. So what would you say in terms of Fisher's... Fisher was
looking at the Disequilibrium Foundations of Equilibrium Economics.
Could you say something about that? How-
Stephen Marglin:
He was looking at what is the key question. We have this concept of
equilibrium and we have a lot of theorems about equilibrium and so
forth, which leaves totally unasked, not to mention unanswered,
well, what happens when you're not an equilibrium? Fisher tried to
come to terms with that in terms of the same high theory that had
been applied to equilibrium analysis, and he had some very
interesting things to say, but as I said, nobody picked up on
it.
Stephen Marglin:
I've always found very interesting the candid comment of the
authors of one of the leading textbooks of graduate economic
theory, which it's called Microeconomic Theory and the authors are
three emanate economists, Mas-Colell, Green and Winston and that
book has been the kind of... A, if not standard graduate text,
since it was published in the nineties, and it's about a thousand
pages, about the same length as mine, but it was very dense
mathematics, 990 of which are devoted to the analysis of
equilibrium and about 10 pages to dynamics, that is what happens
outside of equilibrium. And the authors are very clear about this.
They say, "Well, we know a lot about equilibrium. We have a lot of
good theory about equilibrium. We don't know much about
disequilibrium, so we won't say anything about it," which has
always struck me about as akin to the joke about the drunk and the
lamppost who's looking for his lost car keys and he is looking
under the lamppost because there's light there, not because he
thinks the keys are there.
Speaker 1:
Yeah. I think I remember a textbook Crepes on game theory, where it
in the textbook, I think he pointed out that we have these concepts
of equilibrium, but we don't actually think that that's what we
observe. We don't actually observe empirically the equilibrium
predicted in Nash or whatever. I guess that the response would be
that this is about modeling.
Speaker 1:
I wanted to talk to you about this anyway, but economics, we see
this world, which is just so complex, and things going up and down
and many people happy and many people unhappy, and as I think about
economics the idea is a great economist will pick out some
simplifying assumptions, and then work through a model which
captures some insight, but the assumptions aren't necessarily
simplifying, they're not accurate.
Stephen Marglin:
Absolutely.
Speaker 1:
So it raises the question of how do we judge our assumptions? One
could say, "Well, it's the lamppost, but we don't really have a
good grasp on disequilibrium, so we'll do the best, we'll use
equilibrium and that'll be our simplifying assumption," in a sense.
That might be the response.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah, but it turns out that is my judgment and I offer Raising
Keynes as the defense of my judgment. That's not a very useful
assumption for understanding the macroeconomic fluctuations,
depression, growth, the things we really... are not the only things
we're interested in, but among the top 10 of what we're actually
interested in about how the economy functions.
Stephen Marglin:
So I agree with you completely. All modeling involves some
simplifications, mine certainly does and the question is, are those
simplifying assumptions appropriate to what the questions are at
issue. So in terms of what are the questions at issue, I think the
overarching question, the Keynes theoretical question is, is there
a self regulating mechanism in a capitalist economy which produces
an efficient allocation of resources, provided there are no, what I
call warts on the body of capitalism, that is imperfections like
monopoly, oligopoly, trade unions, government intervention, et
cetera.
Stephen Marglin:
So the idealization is an economy of small agents with no power to
set prices, but are responding to markets, et cetera and the
argument is that in that economy, the mainstream argument before
Keynes and today was and is that there is a self regulating
mechanism, vaguely speaking, Adam Smith's invisible hand, that
produces an efficient allocation of resources, including and
chiefly, full employment, that is a job for every willing worker.
Corollary to that is, "Well, if you observe unemployment, it must
be because of some imperfection in the economy, some wart on the
body of capitalism and that leads then to a policy stance, which is
excise the warts."
Stephen Marglin:
And this is not just theory because this was the theory behind the
move towards deregulation that started, not with Ronald Reagan, as
it's usually often... Well, not usually, but often associated, but
with Jimmy Carter. So it was a bipartisan effort with the backing
of the new classical economics that was taking over in the 1970s
and 1980s and culminated in the financial deregulation of the late
1990s under, not Ronald Reagan or George Bush, but Bill
Clinton.
Stephen Marglin:
I think arguably that was certainly one of the contributing causes
to the great recession of 2008, with its long recovery period. We
didn't really recover from that recession to the end of the Obama
administration.
Stephen Marglin:
So these are not just... You we'd say, "Well, it's what difference
does it make? We know the world is not perfectly competitive. We
know they are always imperfection, so why are we interested in
analyzing an economy where a model, it's not an economy, it's the
model of an economy in which the warts have been removed?" And I
think the clear answer is because it's that model which has
produced very bad policies of laissez-faire and deregulation based
on the idea that the economy isn't self-regulated.
Speaker 1:
Right. And I think if you looked at AFDC, Aid to Families with
Dependent Children, it also, I think, was counter to this
laissez-faire viewpoint and it was also acts during Clinton.
Stephen Marglin:
That's exactly right. Yes, that's exactly right. Yeah.
Speaker 1:
So I know quite a few young people who are not economists, and I
think that if they were to hear that this was a alternative
economics book or approach and that it was dealing with
unemployment, they would say, "Oh, okay, well then you're talking
about racism and domination by capitalists of people who are not
like them, and as the..." at least these are the young people that
I speak to, "this shows the Smith of rugged individualism and it's
all wrong and people need to be nicer to each other," and they
would be surprised to hear that in an alternative course is not one
about racism or capitalist domination.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, if I were giving my introductory course that I gave in the
early years of the century, this would be one piece of it and not
the whole course and all the things that you mentioned would figure
certainly in that course, I don't know, I'm not pretending this is
the whole story.
Speaker 1:
Gotcha.
Stephen Marglin:
I think the mainstream would say, "Well, racism is a wart of the
body of capitalism. We're not racists and we're against racism and
we want racism removed, and if we can succeed, it's not an economic
issue, it's a..." Famously the Nobel prize winner, Gary Becker
attributed racism to a taste for discrimination. If we can just get
people's tastes to be a little better, then we can eliminate
discrimination. So yeah, this is not my textbook on economics, this
Raising Keynes.
Speaker 1:
I gotcha. I understand. And it shares a lot... In a sense it's
making its job difficult because it wants to show enduring
unemployment without any of those things.
Stephen Marglin:
Exactly.
Speaker 1:
Right. So I was thinking about how is this the same and how is it
different than... I was thinking about comparing your text to an
advanced undergrad, or graduate textbook. You're taking this model
approach, this very precise approach where you lay out your
assumptions very clearly and you work them through, you've got
individual decision making organized around and the economy is
driven a lot by profit maximization?
Stephen Marglin:
No.
Speaker 1:
And you have different layers of models. I don't know what else is
similar, but then if we start to think about the differences, I
have a list of them too, but why don't you tell us. If I missed any
of the similarities and also we can start talking about some of the
differences.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, no, I think it may be even more, it's not mathematical, but
more careful in terms of letting of assumptions and so forth than
other books.
Speaker 1:
Yeah, that's true.
Stephen Marglin:
So I plead guilty to that.
Speaker 1:
I agree with you.
Stephen Marglin:
But I mean the differences, I think the main theoretical difference
is that I recognize the problems caused by super imposing Keynes'
novel idea, which is that, we can get into why this case, but that
this new concept that he introduces of aggregate demand, why that
matters and why it complicates things enormously and why it
necessitates a whole different method, which is not starting from
equilibrium, but starting from the processes that work when the
economy is not in equilibrium and in a sense, asking the question,
"Well, do these processes lead to an equilibrium? If so, what kind
of equilibrium? how is it different from the standard equilibrium
that is studied in a framework which doesn't take account of the
processes at work?"
Stephen Marglin:
So those are all the theoretical questions of a general nature and
then I do get into some of the more nitty gritty of Keynes'
assumptions, especially about how interest rates are [inaudible
00:30:18] and how consumption is determined and how investment is
determined, where I'm basically following as much as I can Keynes,
but at certain points, argue that Keynes didn't get it right and
got wrong and here's what we have to do to get it right.
Speaker 1:
Exactly.
Stephen Marglin:
And then there are places where I think it's important to try to
bring in data and real experience in order to actually test how
useful these theories are. Are they conclusive tests? No, I
wouldn't argue that, but I think they're very rarely the case that
an empirical test in economics is conclusive.
Speaker 1:
I gree with that. I would agree with that, yes. And the way that
this plays out is the model is more dynamic than comparative
statics so-
Stephen Marglin:
Because it's looking at the processes.
Speaker 1:
Exactly. So if our listeners aren't familiar, how would you
describe the orthodox approach to change, which is really
comparative statics?
Stephen Marglin:
Well, I can describe because I did it myself for many years and
it's a useful product, it's useful technique.
Speaker 1:
Absolutely.
Stephen Marglin:
But you have to understand its limits. What is the technique? Well,
for example, here's a critical question for Keynes and for
Keynesians and for anti Keynesians, what is the consequence of a
change in wages? What happens if wages change because the argument
that started... Well, I don't think it started there, but certainly
prominent in the great depression and the analysis of the great
depression was that, well, wages are too high. If only wages would
fall, then everything would be okay. We would be back to the
nirvana of full employment and all would be well. How does the
mainstream analyze a fall in wages?
Stephen Marglin:
What they do is they set up two universes. Universe A is the same
as universe B, except in universe A, the wage rate, now this is a
simplification of just one wage rate, the wage rate is $20 per hour
in universe B the wage rate is $15 an hour. So the analysis then
looks at how much employment and how far are we from full
employment in those two universes?
Speaker 1:
That works out an equilibrium in both cases.
Stephen Marglin:
Works out an equilibrium. That equilibrium in each universe is
completely static. Universe A is totally unchanging. Universe B is
totally unchanging [inaudible 00:33:27] time.
Speaker 1:
Exactly.
Stephen Marglin:
If you want to look at change, you do interplanetary travel.
Speaker 1:
Yeah, that's interesting.
Stephen Marglin:
You get on a spaceship and you go from universe A to universe B and
that's how you analyze change and the argument is, "Well, if you
have enough universes with different wages in them, one of them
will have full employment." Well, that's a very different argument,
actually, from what it means in everyday language to ask the
question, "What happens if the wage falls from $20 to $15?"
Speaker 1:
Right. We want a narrative, something continuous.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, yeah, and something that's taking place in real time. And
it's a different question with a different answer. And Keynes was
asking, I think that's the question that people were interested in,
the second question, but the analysis of economists was all about
the first question and it gave the wrong answer to the second
question. So that's why you need a framework in which you actually
trace through the consequences of the wage being today $20 and
tomorrow being $15 six months from now or whatever.
Speaker 1:
Right.
Stephen Marglin:
That's the fundamental difference in framework between analyzing
real time changes and comparative static. Now, does that mean
comparative static is useless?
Speaker 1:
I understand.
Stephen Marglin:
No, it's a very useful technique, but you got to know what
questions it is useful for and why it's not useful for the
particular question of, "If the wage is $20 today and we lower that
to $15 tomorrow, what will be the consequences for employment?"
Speaker 1:
Right. Partly because the path will determine where you end up.
Stephen Marglin:
The path will determine where you end up. People start today with
debts that they incurred on a basis of a $20 wage and now they're
being asked to pay those debts with a wage which hasn't changed
between today and tomorrow, but they're being asked to pay those
debts with a $15 wage. So all kinds of things change and they do
affect the outcome and more important, not just theoretically,
that's what happened in the great depression, which was the
occasion for Keynes to rethink his own ideas and to write the
general theory.
Speaker 1:
I think another way to say this or another level of dynamic versus
static, is to say that your models are "overdetermined," that there
are more equations than unknowns?
Stephen Marglin:
Well, that's what causes the problem in the first place. When you
introduce this concept of aggregate demand, you're adding one more
equation without any more variables, so you can't even apply the
static analysis. You can't apply it in the same old way anyway, so
you're driven, in my view, to a dynamic analysis, but even if it
was some way of resolving that as-
Speaker 1:
Modigliani.
Stephen Marglin:
Yes, that still doesn't get you off the hook because there's all
these issues as to why a change in real time is not the same as a
change between universes.
Speaker 1:
Right. So you say this is page... Well, I don't know the page
number, I've written down, but I can't read it. "Keynes' is
critical endeavor was to establish that a perfectly competitive
market system would not normally provide full employment if left to
its own devices."
Speaker 1:
We chatted a bit about this on email. One of the things about
you're being very honest about what you're doing here, that sounds
like Keynes already knows what he wants to show, and it has a
political charge to it, and he's now getting a model or a way of
thinking which explains something that he believes politically. So
you might say it's ideological and you might think there's
something wrong about that.
Stephen Marglin:
I'm with you all the way to, "There's something wrong about it." I
think that we all have ideology. We tempted to say, "You have
ideology, I have truth," but we all have ideology because there's
always these things that we can't prove and we have intuitions
about and we have beliefs about, and we have views about, but we
can't prove them logically because in some cases they may be
unprovable, and in some cases we just haven't got there yet, but we
need to act in any case. So in that sense, we all have ideology.
And with Schumpeter, Keynes's rival, as it were, certainly saw
himself as Keynes' rival, I'm not sure that Keynes returned the
favor, but Schumpeter was a great economist and is, like Keynes,
going through cycles and I think his stock is on the upturn
now.
Speaker 1:
Is it? Okay.
Stephen Marglin:
And deservedly so. I think he was very good economist with a lot
important things to say.
Speaker 1:
A lot about dynamics.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah, and one of the things he said was he has this two part, I
would say there's really a three part division, but it doesn't
matter. There's what he calls the pre-analytic vision, which he
rants is, one might say, I would not, and I hope you would not, say
tainted by ideology, but which is ideological in part. And then the
theory is what elaborate in order to work out that vision and I
think a good economist, you try to separate that theory from the
vision in the sense that you want it to survive and you want to be
able to argue it to people who don't share your pre-analytic
vision.
Stephen Marglin:
So I think that's what Keynes was doing. He had this vision, this
intuition, if you will, that, and this was hard come by, because as
he says himself, he was brought up in this old school and the hard
part for him was getting rid of the old ideas, which didn't allow
for long term unemployment or any departures that were more than
momentary from full employment and there he was faced like the rest
of the world with the Great Depression and what do you make of it?
And he rethought his vision, and then, as you say, I think was
groping for the model and it took him several years, much less than
10 years I took on Raising Keynes, but it took him several years to
figure out the theory, and it's an unanswerable question.
Stephen Marglin:
Keynes only survived 10 years after the publication, the General
Theory, much of that time he was ill, the rest of it, basically,
most of it, was World War II and he was absorbed in practical
issues of British policy in the war, but it's an interesting
question. If he had survived another 10 years, what he would've
made of the General Theory and what a second edition of the General
Theory might have looked like. We don't know that.
Speaker 1:
Yeah. I think my understanding is that there's a sense in which
Keynes gave his life to the public good, in the sense that he was
at Bretton Woods when he was very ill and he died just after
that.
Stephen Marglin:
Yeah, he died in spring of '46. So yeah, he was very ill by then
and he'd been ill really since I think '38, is when he was first
hospitalized and there are pictures of him in the [inaudible
00:41:49] period. He had a heart condition and there are pictures
of him smoking cigarettes.
Speaker 1:
Right. Oh, it just kills you.
Stephen Marglin:
And [inaudible 00:41:58] they didn't know.
Speaker 1:
Right, I know. Yeah, the famous picture of the Tour de France,
where the guys were smoking on their bike. Well, you talked about,
he needed to get rid of his old ideas and I think my impression of
this book is that I think that many times, to me, the left can just
criticize, criticize, criticize, or attack, attack, attack.
Speaker 1:
What's not done so much or so effectively is constructing an
alternative model, and I think that this book does a great job of
working through showing the flaws in the way that one has been
brought up thinking in economics and building another approach or
the start of another approach, not just attacking, but building up
an alternative approach, which I think it's very exciting. And
congratulations. I think the main reason to read it would be that
you find it interesting, which is what I did, but it also, I'm
hoping that it does serve as a springboard. Thank you so much,
Steve.
Stephen Marglin:
Well, thank you very much and thank you for the compliment at the
end, because that's exactly what I was trying to do and I'm glad I
succeeded at least with one reader. I do hope that it is the start
of something. It is meant to be that and I hope it does serve that
purpose. So thank you very much for this opportunity to talk about
it with you.
Speaker 1:
The pleasure of mine and you're welcome. Thanks so much. Okay. Bye
Steve.